Financial History 100th Edition Double Issue (Spring/Summer 2011) | Page 13

Educators’ Perspective of irony. According to Miller, although Schumpeter’s graduate students “were reflexively hostile to his message, he nevertheless ‘slyly got across one point after another’… Irony served as a battering ram with which to open minds.” By initially appearing to attack capital­ © Bettmann/CORBIS actually the driving force behind Schumpeter. However, the prevailing sentiment during the 1930s, especially at universities such as Harvard, favored socialism over capitalism. Schumpeter, realizing that a direct assault on socialism would have little effect, resorted to a strategy Economist Joseph Alois Schumpeter (1883–1950). ism, he was able to put arguments across in favor of capitalism that the unsuspecting left-leaning intellectual would never have had the patience to consider in a work that was obviously attacking socialism. One of Schumpeter’s students described this as the Mark Anthony technique. “By coming first to ‘bury Caesar not to praise him’ (capitalism is doomed) he was able to get people to read him who would otherwise not have sat still for a moment under his teaching. ‘Brutus’ moreover is ‘an honorable man’ (socialism is workable). Having conceded that much he was then able to insinuate one of the most able defenses of capitalism ever published.” Muller notes that in irony “the stated may be the opposite of the intended.” Thus when someone reads CSD without recognizing the ironic intent, the message is totally lost and Schumpeter appears to be contradictory and illogical. Though many of today’s quantitatively trained economists have little use or patience for irony, they could benefit from a reading of CSD in its proper context. Schumpeter gave the best reason for reading CSD in the preface to the second edition (1946) where he wrote, “Now this is precisely where I wanted to serve the reader. I did want to make him think.” At least one reviewer of CSD in the 1940s understood Schumpeter’s ironic intent. Fritz Machlup’s review in The American Economic Review described CSD as “a humorous-ironic rococo.” While the humor in CSD is obvious, the irony is not. Let’s look at a couple of examples of Schumpeterian humor. When commenting on Marx’s contempt for the idea that those with superior intelligence, who are more energetic workers and savers, become capitalists, Schumpeter hilariously asserts that “to call for a guffaw is no doubt an excellent method of disposing of an uncomfortable truth, as every politician knows to his profit.” Later on he takes another jab at Marx: “…there is little reason to believe that this socialism [as defined by Schumpeter] will mean the ad