Financial History Issue 112 (Winter 2015) | Page 23

mere 2% of the August 1786 requisition.2 Ever since the war began, hard money in the form of internationally accepted gold and silver coins had been in short supply throughout the states. At the time, Americans relied on other countries for specie, with Spain’s gold dollar being especially popular. As these coins passed overseas to pay for imported goods and repay foreign loans, Congress tried to make up the deficit by printing paper dollars, called “Continentals,” but stopped in 1779 after their value collapsed. By 1781, a Continental was worth half a cent and even Congress refused to take them.3 During the war, state-issued paper money did not fare much better. Most suffered hyperinflation. People wanted hard money or paper backed by something of more certain value that a shaky government’s doubtful promises. The states Pennsylvania — but they did so as a majority faction that was sensitive to manipulable shifts in popular opinion. In 1782, when an all-but-bankrupt Congress stopped paying interest on its domestic debt, Pennsylvania began issuing state certificates of interest on that debt to public creditors in its state in place of the unpaid interest. It then accepted them back in partial payment for a newly-imposed tax and credited the certificates toward its requisition instead of paying hard money to Congress. Once issued, Congress no longer owned the interest covered by the certificate but never obtained the hard cash that it needed to pay its other creditors or fund on-going operations. Further, until redeemed in payment of taxes, the certificates circulated as a form of paper money within Pennsylvania. This stimulated the cash-strapped local econ- Collection of the Museum of American Finance States are in the habit of discussing and refusing compliance with them at their option.”1 Most of the nation’s war-related debts were owed to Americans, however, and represented the collective obligations of all the states. If Congress failed to repay them, then the states could step in to take care of their own citizens and, by doing so, supplant Congress in the hearts, minds and wallets of their people. At the time, this represented an ultimate threat to federal union. The scheme was simple and the results potentially debilitating for the central government. In every state, Congress owed money to public creditors: persons holding bonds or other securities issued during the war for money, goods or services. Many of these securities — which originally went to a large number to lenders, suppliers and veterans — had passed into the hands of a small number of speculators, who purchased them at a discount. In turn, the states owed annual requisitions to Congress, and public creditors owed taxes to their states. As long as Congress was unable to pay public creditors, the states could accept national securities from their citizens as payment for state taxes and apply them at face value toward their requisition