Financial History Issue 112 (Winter 2015) | Page 25

to him. “Paper bills of credit,” he complained, give “the shadow for the substance of a debt.”7 Even less restrained in their words, Jay, Virginia Congressman James Madison and many other leading nationalists denounced state-issued paper money in the strongest terms. Arguing against its issuance by his state in 1786, for example, Madison lectured Virginia’s legislature that paper money would “destroy confidence between individuals” and “disgrace republican gov[ernmen]ts in the eyes of mankind.”8 Yet under the Articles of Confederation, Congress was as powerless to prevent states from issuing paper money as it was to stop an incoming tide. Creditors like Washington, who feared that cheap paper money would erode the value of fixed investments, were swimming against that tide in trying to prevent state legislatures from authorizing it. At most, opponents could try to limit its use to paying taxes or have it secured by something of value, such as state-owned land. The dam broke in 1786, when seven states emitted paper money. “Pennsylvania and North Carolina took the lead in this folly,” Madison wrote in August to Thomas Jefferson, who was then serving as America’s ambassador in Paris. Most of the initial emissions incorporated limits that helped them to hold value at least initially, but in debtor-controlled Rhode Island, which made its paper money legal tender for virtually all public and private debts, the bottom dropped out of the currency’s value almost immediately and hard money was driven underground. “Supplies were withheld from the market, the shops were shut, popular meetings ensued and the state remains in a sort of convulsion,” Madison told Jefferson. “Depreciation is inevitable” in every state with paper money, Madison predicted, yet driven by popular factions, he feared that more states would join others in printing “this fictitious money.”9 Madison perceived a pattern in the rush to paper. State governments with the fewest checks and balances tended to act first and in the most extreme manner. Pennsylvania and Rhode Island, for example, placed all power in the legislature, with the executive and the judiciary serving at its pleasure. In contrast, he observed in his letter to Jefferson, Maryland held back because the state Senate — presumably because of the long terms, indirect selection process and property qualifications of its members — stood as “a bar to paper in that state.” But as “the clamor for [paper money] is now universal, and as the periodical election of the Senate happens at this crisis,” Madison added with his customary pessimism, Maryland’s next Senate will likely surrender.10 This experience confirmed his view that America needed a balanced national government that could check the power of state excesses and majority factions. From Paris, Jefferson had sent Madison a shipment of treatises on government by European political philosophers that arrived early in 1786. Now he began trolling through them in earnest for arguments in support of his view. Expressing similar sentiments at the same time, Washington wrote to former Congressman Theordorick Bland in August 1786, complaining about “the present alarming troubles in Rhode Island.”11 Writing to Jay on the same day, Washington added, “What a triumph for the advocates of despotism to find that we are incapable of governing ourselves, and that systems founded on the basis of equal liberty are merely ideal and fallacious! Would to God that wise measures may be taken in time to avert the consequences we have but too much reason to apprehend.”12 For nationalists, Rhode Island became an object lesson in the dangers of excess democracy and a clarion call for constitutional reform. Proponents of paper money pointed to the success of other states in preserving its value, but critics saw it from Madison’s perspective and, all but giving up on the states, turned toward the nation for salvation. Referring to related developments in New Jersey, Madison asked James Monroe earlier in 1786, “Is it possible with such an example before our eyes of impotency in the federal system, to remain skeptical with regard to the necessity of infusing more energy into it?”13 Echoing these sentiments in his August letter to Jay, Washington wrote, “I do not conceive we can exist long as a nation, without having lodged somewhere a power which will pervade the whole Union in an energetic a manner.” Significantly, he then added, “Retired as I am from the world, I frankly acknowledge I cannot feel myself an unconcerned spectator.”14 The specter of unpaid debt, and the states replacing Congress as the functional center of governing authority drew Washington, Madison, Jay and the other nationalists to the fore — driving them, and their country, to a new Constitution and a more perfect union that would forever change the nature of government.  Pulitzer prize-winning historian Edward J. Larson is University Professor of history and holds the Hugh & Hazel Darling Chair in Law at Pepperdine University and an inaugural Library Fellow at the Fred W. Smith National Library for the Study of George Washington in Mount Vernon, VA. This article has been adapted from his latest book, The Return of George Washington, 1783–1789 (HarperCollins, 2014), with the permission of the publisher. Notes 1. George Washington to John Jay, Aug. 15, 1786, PGW CS 4: 213. 2. Ray Raphael, Constitutional Myths: What We Ge