Financial History Issue 117 (Spring 2016) | Page 39

BY MICHAEL A. MARTORELLI   BOOK REVIEW America’s Bank: The Epic Struggle to Create The Federal Reserve By Roger Lowenstein Penguin Press, 2015 335 pages, $29.95 Even readers familiar with the origins of the America’s third central bank will benefit from Roger Lowenstein’s America’s Bank: The Epic Struggle to Create The Federal Reserve System. They will especially appreciate his decision to devote equal time to the financial crises that convinced reformers of the need for some kind of central bank, and the legislative maneuvering that finally led to passage of the Federal Reserve Act. Lowenstein first tells how financial panics in the late 19th and early 20th centuries prompted would-be reformers to push for changes in the way the nation’s fragmented and unorganized banking system allocated credit and managed (or didn’t manage) the supply of money. After the election of 1896, a group of academics, bankers and industrialists (operating as the Indianapolis Monetary Commission) proposed a set of reforms that would allow the supply of money and credit to expand and contract to reflect economic conditions. But political and economic leaders in Washington and on Wall Street were not ready to support such reforms, which included an expanded role for the federal government in regulating the financial system. In 1902, Secretary of the Treasury Lyman Gage called explicitly for a government central bank, thus formally and publicly repudiating President Andrew Jackson’s famous veto of such an institution in 1835. Another financial panic in 1907 once again revealed the major fault lines that existed in the nation’s banking and monetary system. Senator Nelson Aldrich, Chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, pushed for the establishment of a National Monetary Commission to recommend specific reforms. The author details the nature of that committee’s investigative efforts during the following two years. Its final report, published in early 1911, called for the creation of a National Reserve Association of the United States. Lowenstein then shows how the wrangling over the elements of this Aldrich Plan was only the prelude to the more meaningful debate that emerged as Congress attempted to transform it into a law. The American Bankers Association, the National Citizens’ (i.e. Businessmens’) League for the Promotion of a Sound Banking System and presidential candidates William Jennings Bryan, Howard Taft, Theodore Roosevelt and Woodrow Wilson all weighed in with suggestions for changes. The Democratic Party’s consolidation of political power following the elections of 1912 was not accompanied by the emergence of a consensus regarding some key elements of a potential banking reform plan. For example, forces inside and outside of government continued to argue over the ownership and powers of geographically dispersed Reserve Banks, as well as the need for, the makeup and the authority of a “capstone” central bank. President Wilson tackled other economic problems before turning his full attention to banking reform. By June 1913, he had made his ultimate views on many questions clear enough to permit Congressman Carter Glass and Senator Robert Owen to introduce companion bills that had the President’s full support. After a brief period of reconc