Financial History Issue 124 (Winter 2018) | Page 11

MUSEUM NEWS   build consensus. You had to understand the perspectives of others. Your influence was mostly a function of the credibility you could earn and by the quality of your ideas. It wasn’t enough to believe you were right. This ability to attract talented people willing to do these jobs is not something you could take for granted. It’s a fragile thing. Idealism about public service is vulnerable to the extreme tribalism of our politics and the systematic demeaning of the integrity and competence of pub- lic servants. When the experienced and the idealistic leave and the new ones are deterred from coming, you risk long-term damage to the effectiveness of govern- ment, at a time when most of the hard things we face can’t be solved only by the innovations of the market, but require better policy and more effective execution. As impressive to me as the people I got to work with at Treasury and the Fed was the approach to policymaking, and decision-making, that I experienced. Bob Rubin ran an exacting and thrilling process of decision-making, and this was true for the President with whom I worked most closely, as well. This approach to choices, to policymaking, to decision-making, was characterized by a relentless search for the best of the bad options, skepticism of the easy or politically expedient choice, a rich debate among a group of people with very diverse skills and experiences, no tolerance for internal politicking, and the encouraging of challenge and dissent. It was safe to admit uncertainty. In fact, humility in the face of what we could not be sure of was the price for a seat at the table. It was a competition for ideas, but without people being paralyzed, frozen, afraid to act. At the New York Fed, I found a ter- rifically capable group of people, and of course I had the exceptional fortune of working with Hank Paulson and Ben Bernanke through the most harrowing parts of the financial crisis. We trusted each other. We debated everything. We worked together, not against each other. We approached these choices by honor- ing the tradition Bob used to call — or still calls — probabilistic decision-making, which involves examining the relative chances of the full range of policy out- comes, including the most forbidding; trying to choose the best policy option, that had the highest expected value, the option that, if you were wrong, still left you with some freedom to change course. His lessons in preserving optionality are legenda