Financial History Issue 129 (Spring 2019) | Page 20

supported their businesses directly. New investors were investing in businesses they knew because they were customers of those businesses. By the mid-1920s, it was possible to sit in one’s home, place a phone call to the local brokerage office and have a trade executed on Wall Street. Finally, in 1928, the NYSE embarked on an aggressive public relations campaign aimed at popularizing the “peo- ple’s market.” As the market was reaching its peak, the Big Board embarked on a media campaign to attract new investors, otherwise known as novices. What is fascinating about this period was that investors were flocking to the markets even though they remained exceptionally opaque institutions. Insider trading and price manipulation were not illegal. The list of ploys that were permit- ted is astonishing: for example, one com- mon practice was to send simultaneous buy and sell trades to the same broker to create a fictitious price. As the demand for and success of industrials increased, and interest in investing spread to more and more parts of the population, the resulting squeeze of investors by insiders proved to be politically unsustainable. In the 1910s, a series of securities regula- tions were enacted that sought to protect minority shareholders in almost every US state. The pressure caused the NYSE to act to preempt government intervention. But the exchange moved unevenly, initially banning only the most egregious practices. In 1913, the practice of buying and sell- ing simultaneously was banned, although using customers’ funds to manipulate prices to members’ advantage was only “con- demned.” Only in 1917 did the NYSE enjoin its members from buying tomorrow’s head- lines from hungry newspaper reporters, and it took another year after that for the exchange to forbid the deliberate circulation of rumors intended to move prices. Given the range of predatory prac- tices to which the unsuspecting investor could be subjected, it is hardly surpris- ing that many potential novice market players opted not to participate. There is little evidence that these protections were enforced, and the legal obligations of cor- porations toward their shareholders were being undermined by a race to the bottom in the laws of general incorporation. Despite the questionable market reforms and remaining opaqueness, FIGURE 1: Margin Loans by Lender, 1919–1930 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (US), Banking and Monetary Statistics, 1914–1943 (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC, 1943), 494, table 139. the conditions had been set and market capitalism exploded. Regional exchanges opened in Detroit, Cleveland, San Fran- cisco, Chicago and Los Angeles. Besides the aforementioned New York Curb Exchange, similar exchanges emerged near other regional exchanges. O’Sullivan reports that the number of traded securities increased significantly from 1880 through 1930. The number of stocks traded across all US exchanges increased from 916 in 1900 to 1,340 in 1915 and 2,659 in 1930. These changes were met with increases in investors. Gardiner C. Means’s esti- mates from 1900 were based on the total number of “book stockholders,” or the sum of the number of people holding each individual stock. This overcounts the total number of individual owners because the same person might hold positions in more than one company, in which case that person would be counted twice. But this method is good for examining trends, 18    FINANCIAL HISTORY  |  Spring 2019  | www.MoAF.org as the total number of individual inves- tors must be highly correlated with the number of book stockholders, a number that quadrupled between 1900 and 1930. Specifically, the number of reported book owners increased from 4.4 million in 1900 to 7.5 million in 1913, and then to 12 mil- lion in 1920 and 18 million in 1928. Means estimated the total number of individuals by dividing book owners by four and tri- angulated with income tax records. Between four million and six million individuals owned shares in corporations in 1927, perhaps three million to five mil- lion of them in public corporations. And based on income tax records, there are reasons to believe that the “few hundred men” controlling the market in 1900 were being diluted. From 1916 to 1921, the top 25,000 highest-earning Americans saw their ownership share of corporate Amer- ica decrease from 57% to 37%. During the same period, individuals who didn’t make the top 100,000 highest