Financial History Issue 130 (Summer 2019) | Page 28
that their debts would be repaid from their
future wages.
By 1900, “chattel loans,” cash advances
secured by a lien on the borrower’s per-
sonal property, and “salary loans,” secured
by an assignment of the borrower’s future
wages, had become a common source of
credit for urban, working-class laborers.
Buying goods “on time” or “on install-
ment” had also grown to be part of every-
day life. Merchants sold clothing, furni-
ture and sewing machines on credit to
working-class buyers, who agreed to pay
back the sales price plus credit charges in
regular installments, and risk repossession
of their purchases if they failed to repay
the debt.
In this period, the law governing house-
hold loans was ancient and varied from
state to state. Even as legal control over
other matters of economic life had begun
to move from the states to the federal gov-
ernment, a hodgepodge of state and local
law continued to govern the business of
making and collecting small loans in the
early 20th century.
Small cash loans were essentially out-
lawed in most states because of restrictive
lending laws that dated back to the 19th
century. Lenders could not make a profit
if they charged interest at the low rates
allowed under these statutes, known as
“usury laws.” In contrast, selling goods
“on time” was hardly regulated at all,
thanks to a longstanding legal distinc-
tion between cash loans and sales credit.
Although merchants often charged one
cash price to customers who paid upfront
and another to customers buying on time,
the law did not treat the difference between
these prices as interest on a loan under the
judge-made “time-price” doctrine. Cash
loans were subject to state usury laws, but
sales of goods on time were not.
Over the course of the 20th century,
however, the states adopted new rules to
govern small-sum lending, through a pro-
cess that was both national and, yet, highly
localized. Nationally, lenders formed pro-
fessional trade associations to lobby for
their interests, and the largest companies
operated branches across multiple states.
Reformers likewise founded large national
organizations, as well as nationwide fed-
erations of local groups, to draft legisla-
tion and lobby for change. These groups
then attempted to guide the development
Draft of the Uniform Small Loan Act, 1923.
of lending regulations across the country,
often through the creation of model state
laws drafted by experts in the field. Legal
localism persisted, however.
Even after the New Deal’s reconfigura-
tion of federal-state relations in the 1930s
and the growth of the federal government
in the decades that followed, the states
retained primary authority over small
loans. As a result, each state followed
its own course, but often in imitation of
a model law or another state’s strategy.
Most began by limiting the reach of credi-
tors seeking to collect unpaid debts before
eventually enacting substantive rules
restricting loan terms and then, finally,
wrestling with the problem of how to
ensure the law’s enforcement. The phases
of small sum lending regulation also
tracked shifting ideas about the proper
role of the state in the marketplace, as well
as changes in the relative strength of state
and federal regulatory power.
The Uniform Small Loan Law drafted
in the 1910s, for example, reflected that
era’s faith in the ability of expert reformers
to curtail abusive business practices and
the reformers’ trust in the power of better
legal infrastructure to enable the flow of
26 FINANCIAL HISTORY | Summer 2018 | www.MoAF.org
private capital into the market. The law
also affirmed the traditional primacy of the
states in regulating this form of commerce.
Indeed, even after the federal government
joined the fray in the 1960s and then
reduced the states’ power over some forms
of lending in the decades that followed, the
states still retained significant authority
over the governance of small loans.
For most of the past century, campaigns
for the adoption and enforcement of new
lending rules played out in dozens of
statehouses and in hundreds of state and
local courthouses, rather than in a few
centralized venues. In each state, local
players and state-level political dynamics
could shift the balance in deciding when
and how to police small-sum loans, and
so the tempo and rhythm of legal change
varied considerably from place to place.
To date, historians of law and Ameri-
can capitalism have underemphasized the
challenges of state-level economic gov-
ernance in the modern era. The litera-
ture on the legal history of 20th-century
capitalism is large and growing, including
studies on diverse topics such as taxation,
the stock market, long-haul trucking and
consumer credit.
Yet, although there is a rich body of
work on state and local governance of
the marketplace during the 19th century,
most historians of the 20th century have
focused on national state-building and
federal economic regulation, particularly
when considering the 1930s and subse-
quent decades. They have shown how
national policy privileged particular
groups and forms of economic growth,
and shaped middle-class markets for
housing, labor, education and consumer
goods. But even as the federal government
expanded over the course of the century,
states and localities retained primary con-
trol over many key aspects of commercial
life, operating within the American system
of divided regulatory authority known as
“federalism.”
Federalism is the first of three reasons
why governing small-sum lending has
proved to be especially tricky over the
course of the past century. Cash lenders
and their capital have been able to move
easily across state boundaries, operating
in one jurisdiction while lending to bor-
rowers elsewhere by mail. Lenders’ mobil-
ity, coupled with the limited authority