Financial History Issue 133 (Spring 2020) | Page 14

being a move to more efficient, greener and environmentally friendly production. That means that the exact supply chains may change, but they will almost certainly involve multiple countries on different continents. Part of the need for long supply chains comes down to specialization, something that the founder of economics, Adam Smith, discussed over 200 years ago. He described the manufacturing process of a pair of shears, which are needed to clip a fleece from a sheep, and the specialists required. The miner, the builder of the furnace for smelting the ore, the feller of the timber, the burner of the charcoal to be made use of in the smelting-house, the brick-maker, the brick-layer, the workmen who attend the furnace, the mill-wright, the forger, the smith, must all of them join their different arts in order to produce them. Put simply, Smith showed that special- ization works well in production because each expert can work more efficiently by concentrating on a single task. It was another man who supercharged specialization and, with it, globalization. Self-taught 19th-century Scottish econo- mist David Ricardo discovered a phenom- enon known as comparative advantage. It showed that there’s a benefit to trade even when a specialist can do everything better than can others. For example, even if the United States can manufacture every item better and cheaper than all other countries, there is still an advantage for everyone to trade. He also showed that comparative advantage would lead to an increase in total output. That theory supercharged international trade over the last two centuries. We know this by looking at global exports as a percentage of GDP. Because all exports must go somewhere, the total 12    FINANCIAL HISTORY  |  Spring 2020  | www.MoAF.org of all exports from every country must be equal to the total volume of imports. In short, we are safe in looking solely at the export side of the equation, at least in this case. Net exports as a percentage of world GDP grew more than three-fold from 7% in 1827 to 24% in 2014, or almost a quarter of world GDP, according to the recent data. That means trade more than tripled as a portion of economic output. For ref- erence, peak trade hit 26% in 2008. There was one period when trade did decline for a few decades and that also coincided with a period of military con- flict and severe economic downturn in some leading economics. On the eve of World War I in 1913, combined global exports reached the then peak of 14% of global GDP. Then the world went to war, an event that would naturally sty- mie trade. But even after WWI ended, trade kept declining through the 1920s and 1930s. The 1930s, in particular, suffered the