Financial History Issue 129 (Spring 2019) | Page 16
By Daniel C. Munson
Much has been written about the
changes to the American financial sys-
tem and the American economy resulting
from the establishment of the Federal
Reserve Bank in 1913. These writings are
interesting, but they often devolve into
attempts at second-guessing the actions of
the Federal Reserve in response to various
economic conditions—depressions, spec-
ulative bubbles, etc.—with the convenient
perspective of hindsight.
Another way to think about the effects
of the Federal Reserve System is to ask
what changes it has wrought on the behav-
ior of the nation’s citizens. Do our busi-
ness people behave differently because
there is a central bank? This question
can be approached any number of ways,
but one way is to look at similar sets of
economic circumstances occurring with
and without the presence of the Federal
Reserve and observe the behavior of the
market participants.
Market panics can throw these behav-
iors into stark relief. In the same way
that bad weather can expose the skill (or
lack of skill) of ship captains and airplane
pilots, bank failures and liquidity crises
can throw bright light on the actions of a
nation’s financiers.
The panics of the late summer and early
fall of 1907 and 2008 can serve. They were
separated not merely by a clean century
of time, but by the absence (1907) and
the presence (2008) of a powerful central
bank. A look back at the chaos and the
action during those two panics can per-
haps allow us to understand better the
effects of central banking.
The facts surrounding the panics of
1907 and 2008 were different, but in pre-
cipitating features they were the same.
Credit conditions were strained in Octo-
ber 1907 and suddenly came completely
unglued when the Knickerbocker Trust, a
prominent New York bank, was rumored
to have a big book of business with an
over-extended copper mining financier
who went bust attempting to force a
Previous page: Wall Street during
the Panic of 1907.
“short squeeze” in the shares of a com-
pany he controlled. Troubles in 2008 cul-
minated when Lehman Brothers was sunk
by a large pile of lousy mortgages and real
estate investments. In 1907, J. Pierpont
Morgan sent his people to rifle through
the books of the Knickerbocker Trust to
assess if it was salvageable with an emer-
gency loan and, similarly, in 2008 Lehman
Brothers was examined by a number of
potential buyers (including J.P. Morgan
Chase) in the days before its collapse.
The suspension of operations at the
Knickerbocker Trust and the bankruptcy
of Lehman Brothers had similar cascading
effects: there was uncertainty concerning
exactly which financial institutions held
the bad loans and in what amounts, and
this uncertainty led to reduced levels of
lending. Asset prices declined sharply as
the credit necessary to finance asset pur-
chases dried up, and banks tried to call in
loans and refused to make new loans until
they could assess the damage.
The difference for investors is that in
2008 the benefit of being liquid was small.
Interbank overnight rates increased a few
percentage points in the two weeks follow-
ing the collapse of Lehman Brothers, then
dropped precipitously to near zero. Mar-
gin lending rates, strictly limited in scope,
barely budged. Long-dated Treasury secu-
rities, which while liquid do involve put-
ting principal at risk, increased in value
some 15–20% in the ensuing months as
long-term rates declined. But, in general,
those in cash and money market funds
simply sat by and contented themselves
with the thought that they hadn’t lost any
money.
In 1907, however, a liquid investor
unwilling to tie up money for years in
buying depressed common stocks could
still have made some real dough. In the
wake of the closure of the Knickerbocker
Trust, the market that lent short-term
against stock market collateral—the
“call loan,” now the “margin loan” mar-
ket—needed lenders: the prevailing rate
of roughly 6% was not high enough to
induce sufficient supply. (Recall that a 6%
interest rate in 1907 was a “real” rate in
that the gold-backed 1907 US dollar held
and even tended to increase slightly in
value over time.) Trust companies like the
14 FINANCIAL HISTORY | Spring 2019 | www.MoAF.org
Knickerbocker routinely made unsecured
loans to Wall Street brokers, but when the
panic began and Trust depositors began
queueing up to withdraw money, credit
on Wall Street became very tight.
J.P. Morgan’s syndicate of banks sent
funds, but the demand from the illiquid
was insatiable. The nation’s newspapers
reported the dramatic events: on October
22—the day the Knickerbocker Trust sus-
pended operations—the morning call loan
rate of 10% produced insufficient supply,
and by mid-afternoon rates had skyrock-
eted to 60% and later 70%. On October
24, call money rates peaked at 90%. The
following day, call money temporarily
reached 100%. Brokers in Philadelphia
threw up their hands and simply discon-
tinued all trading on margin.
One person’s high borrowing rate is
another’s payday, of course, and the mar-
ket participants holding unencumbered
cash in late 1907 might have felt that
they were indeed living in “the best of
all possible worlds.” Those who could
lend funds to the call loan market did so,
earning 1% on their money in only a few
days. These profitable rates persisted: call
loan rates remained well above 20% into
early November and averaged around 20%
for months afterwards. There was money
made by these same liquid folks in cash-
ing checks and clearing house certificates,
perhaps discounting them significantly
from face value.
My contemporaries may wish to avert
their eyes. The business of charging “usu-
rious” rates to the financially distressed,
the illiquid, is not a pretty sight. Those
solvent souls in 1907 who saw themselves
as fulfilling a useful function—providing
cash at a time when it was needed—had to
know that the country at-large probably
thought of them as vultures.
The financial trauma of October 1907 did
not pass quickly from public conscious-
ness. It became known that the leaders of
the major Wall Street banks, J.P. Morgan
and his colleagues, had decided behind
closed doors which banks and trust com-
panies could be saved and which ones had
to be shuttered. In the days before deposit
insurance, this appeared to be incredible
power wielded by private citizens account-
able only to their shareholders.