Financial History Issue 129 (Spring 2019) | Page 17
Members of the US Congress decided
to investigate this unaccountability. They
held what became known as the Pujo
Hearings, named after Congressman
Arsene Pujo of Louisiana, a House Bank-
ing and Currency subcommittee inquiry
into whether there was a “money trust”
in Wall Street. (“Trust” was both a legal
and a colloquial term used to connote a
concentration of power in any industry
that might need to be broken up. A finan-
cial trust company like the Knickerbocker
Trust, however, was a lightly regulated
bank that paid slightly higher deposit
rates, but that generally took somewhat
more risk with depositors’ money.) The
work of this subcommittee resulted in the
passage of the 16th Amendment autho-
rizing a federal income tax, the Clayton
Anti-Trust Act and the Federal Reserve
Act establishing a central bank, a bank
designed to check the power of J.P. Mor-
gan and his colleagues that would—most
significantly—be empowered to function
as a “lender of last resort.”
The establishment of the Federal
Reserve sought to banish for eternity those
all too conspicuous vultures. By empower-
ing an institution to combat bank panics,
the government made sure such vultures
could never again profit from having
“ready money” in times of panic. Early
on, its leaders were hesitant. But as the
dollar’s link to gold loosened until being
cut entirely in 1971, the Federal Reserve
became increasingly willing to provide
cheap liquidity at any hint of trouble.
Federal Reserve officials like to quote
the classic principles of central banking
promulgated by 19th century British econ-
omist Walter Bagehot, who counseled
that central bankers should—in times of
panic—lend freely against good collateral,
but at a high interest rate. Modern cen-
tral bankers have certainly mastered the
first two of these precepts—lending freely
against good collateral (if mortgages are
considered “good”)—but the third con-
cerning interest rates they seem to ignore
entirely.
Wall Street watched this and gradu-
ally concluded that liquidity does not
pay. In the wake of the Lehman bank-
ruptcy in 2008, when liquid funds were
needed, short-term rates did not spike
Bernard Baruch was young and newly
rich in 1907. He quietly deposited $1
million into a few strapped but solvent
Manhattan banks, and he shipped cash
to a distressed copper mining concern in
Utah while buying up its common stock.
upwards—they declined! Federal Reserve
infusions saw to it.
The lesson was obvious. What was the
point of holding cash for such scarce times
if the Fed could print all any bank needed?
What large financial institution could
afford to tilt against such a policy wind
and do other than “borrow short, lend
long and hope for the best”? A century of
financial gerrymandering has produced a
system that simply does not reward risk-
aversion in any positive way.
The implications of this policy change
extend beyond “solving” the liquidity
problem of the moment. One is the decline
of the currency: The Federal Reserve now
manages interest rates to maximize eco-
nomic growth and employment, meaning
that interest rates are often kept lower
than they would be otherwise, which in
turn requires the Federal Reserve to create
money to bid up the price of government
securities and suppress these rates. (The
call money rate, for example, has never
returned to remotely the levels of October
1907.) All the money and credit creation
required has left the US dollar—now a
“Federal Reserve Note”—a tiny 2% speck
of the gold-backed dollar of 1907, and
gradual devaluation (i.e., “inflation target-
ing”) is now a governmental goal.
The subtle, less visible effect is on the
value of, and the potential returns accru-
ing to, financial prudence. To illustrate, it
helps to recall the actions of a few promi-
nent financial figures from those bygone
days of 1907.
Bernard Baruch was young and newly
rich in 1907. He had made a fortune
speculating on sugar prices, the end of
the Spanish-American War in 1898, and
the Northern Pacific ownership tussle and
short squeeze of 1901. He was, neverthe-
less, a public-spirited man who would
later volunteer his services to the govern-
ment during the World Wars. The fall
of 1907 found him worried about the
markets and holding roughly $2 million
in cash in safe-deposit boxes. When the
panic took hold, he saw his duty to be
in shoring up the nation’s financial con-
dition. He thought of approaching J.P.
Morgan directly with offers of help, but he
knew Morgan regarded him as little more
than a gambler. Baruch instead quietly
deposited $1 million into a few strapped
but solvent Manhattan banks, and he
shipped cash to a distressed copper min-
ing concern in Utah while buying up its
common stock.
Jesse Livermore was also a newly rich
speculator in 1907, but he was somewhat
more flamboyant than his contemporary,
Baruch. Known around Wall Street as the
“Boy Plunger” because of his perennially
youthful appearance and his investing
style, Livermore was alternately barbari-
cally liquid and then bankrupt as his
speculative positions waxed and waned.
(In Wall Street parlance of the day, to
“plunge” was to sink most of one’s assets
into a single speculative position.) Octo-
ber 1907 found him solidly short the mar-
ket, and he was making hundreds of thou-
sands of dollars per day in late October
when the great man, J.P. Morgan himself,
placed a discrete phone call to Livermore
asking him to discontinue his shorting of
the stock market. Livermore complied,
later recalling the significance of Morgan’s
request as part of “a day of days for me,”
one in which his winnings were tallied in
both money and “intangibles.”
Henrietta “Hetty” Green was a mon-
strously rich private investor in 1907. The
sole surviving heiress to a New Bedford,
www.MoAF.org | Spring 2019 | FINANCIAL HISTORY 15