Financial History Issue 129 (Spring 2019) | Page 25
bankruptcies. It provided an excellent
backdrop for the emerging consortium
of the disaffected groups noted above to
push their congressional representatives
to impose a progressive income tax on the
wealthy. In addition to reducing tariffs,
the Wilson-Gorman Act of August 1894
introduced a 2% federal tax on individual
income. Members of both the Populist
and Democratic parties supported the
reduction in tariffs and the concomitant
establishment of a graduated income tax
with a relatively high exemption. Tak-
ing these actions would not disrupt the
level of federal revenue but would shift
the balance of revenue-producers from
the poor to the rich. The validity of that
argument was never tested. In April 1895,
the Supreme Court declared the tax to be
an unapportioned direct one that violated
several clauses of the US Constitution.
This particular version of an income
tax might have died, but the idea for one
certainly did not. Its supporters believed
the Supreme Court had been mistaken in
its ruling. Moreover, they saw the personal
income tax as not only an economic tool
to address some fiscal imbalances, but an
ethical and moral way to raise govern-
ment revenue while limiting the growing
concentration of wealth. In the 1896 cam-
paign for the presidency, the Democratic
standard-bearer William Jennings Bryan
supported an income tax aimed primar-
ily at the wealthiest Americans to replace
the tariffs and excise taxes that were paid
largely by the poorest citizens. Even after
his defeat, the party leaders continued to
push for an income tax. In 1898, House
Democrats’ proposal for an income tax
of 3% on annual incomes over $2,000 was
soundly defeated.
In the midst of the emerging debate
over the income tax, the federal govern-
ment began to report increasingly larger
deficits in each year from 1897 to 1899,
even with the Dingley tariffs at historically
high levels. Restraining federal spending
was difficult, largely due to the need to
fund programs such as the expansion of
the Navy and increases in veterans’ pen-
sion benefits. In the first several years of
the 20th century, members of the Repub-
lican party’s growing progressive wing
came to appreciate the need to consider
new sources of revenue. Another financial
panic in 1907 brought reduced economic
activity, more corporate bankruptcies,
high unemployment and new strains on
the federal budget. By 1909, congressional
progressives had become sufficiently pow-
erful to add an income tax rider to an early
version of the Payne-Aldrich Tariff Act.
On separate occasions since winning
the White House, President Taft had
voiced both support for and opposition
to an income tax. He did not want to see
another challenge to the Supreme Court
over such a fundamental change in fed-
eral policy. Instead, he believed Congress
should pass a constitutional amendment
authorizing a tax on individuals’ income
before actually imposing such a levy. Even
while wrangling over what was to become
the Payne-Aldrich Tarif Act noted ear-
lier, in July 1909, Congress sent to the
states this language for a proposed 16th
Amendment: “The Congress shall have the
power to lay and collect taxes on incomes,
from whatever source derived, without
apportionment among the several States,
and without regard to any census or enu-
meration.” Taft persuaded the conference
committee crafting the final version of
the tariff bill to replace the provision for
an income tax on everyone with one tax-
ing only the income of corporations. As
noted earlier, he signed Payne-Aldrich in
August.
When the 16th Amendment was pro-
posed, conservative lawmakers in Con-
gress doubted it would be ratified by the
required number of 36 of the country’s 48
states. Many failed to recognize the pub-
lic’s dissatisfaction with the complex and
always-changing system of tariffs. Farmers
in the South and West, and Progressives
and Populists in other areas agreed with
the traditional Democratic argument that
tariffs unfairly taxed the poor and drove up
prices for all consumers. President Theo-
dore Roosevelt and his progressive Repub-
lican followers supported the amendment.
Legislators representing manufacturers,
bankers and others involved in the coun-
try’s expanding foreign trade recognized
its role in supporting reductions in tariffs
and other trade barriers. And government
officials of both parties saw the tax as a
way to insure the greater level of federal
revenue they believed would be necessary
to respond satisfactorily to the growing
militarism of Germany and Japan. All
three candidates for President in 1912
supported the amendment. It was no sur-
prise when Delaware acted in February
1913 to become the 36th state to vote for
its ratification.
With that amendment now approved,
Congress used a provision of the afore-
mentioned Underwood-Simmons Act of
October 1913 to impose a progressive indi-
vidual income tax at rates ranging from 1%
to 7%. Tax revenue started to flow to the
individual US Treasury within the year.
Tariffs generated 95% of the US govern-
ment’s revenue in 1790. During the next
120 years, they rarely dipped below 60%
of federal receipts. In 1915, following the
passage of the 16th Amendment, tariffs
contributed only 30% of those receipts.
During the subsequent 102 years they
declined steadily as important sources
of revenue; tariffs now account for less
than 2% of all the funds the government
receives. Meanwhile, the personal and
corporate income taxes formally proposed
in 1909 have recently been contributing
more than 55% of revenue. The so-called
“payroll tax” used to fund the Social Secu-
rity and Medicare programs established
in 1933 and 1965, respectively, provide
another 35%. But that, as they say, is
another story.
Michael A. Martorelli is a Director
Emeritus at Fairmount Partners and a
frequent contributor to Financial His-
tory. He earned his MA in History from
American Military University.
Sources
Baack, Bennett D. and Edward John Ray.
“Special Interests and the Adoption of the
Income Tax in the United States.” The Jour-
nal of Economic History. Vol 45, No. 3, pp.
607–625. September 1985.
Mehrotra, Ajay K. “More Mighty than the
Waves of the Sea: Toilers, Tariffs, and the
Income Tax Movement, 1880–1913.” Labor
History. Vol 45, No. 2, pp. 165–198. May
2004.
Solvick, Stanley D. “William Howard Taft and
the Payne-Aldrich Tariff.” The Mississippi
Valley Historical Review, Vol 50, No. 3, pp.
424–442. December 1963.
Weisman, Steven R. The Great Tax Wars:
Lincoln to Wilson—The Fierce Battles Over
Money and Power That Transformed the
Nation. Simon & Schuster. 2002.
www.MoAF.org | Spring 2019 | FINANCIAL HISTORY 23