Financial History Issue 130 (Summer 2019) | Page 35
THE GREATEST
VICTORIAN
By James Grant
In 1832, Jeremiah Harman, a long-serving
director of the Bank of England, testified
before a parliamentary committee on how
the Bank rose to meet the occasion of the
Panic of 1825. It was a desperate time, and
the Bank lent money in unprecedented
ways.
“We lent it by every possible means,
and in modes that we never had adopted
before,” Harman explained;
we took in stock as security, we pur-
chased exchequer bills, we made
advances on exchequer bills, we not
only discounted outright, but we
made advances on deposit of bills of
exchange to an immense amount; in
short by every possible means consis-
tent with the safety of the Bank; and
we were not upon some occasions over
nice; seeing the dreadful state in which
the public were, we rendered every
assistance in our power.
Bagehot (pronounced Badge-it), who
wrote the still-canonical prescription for
stopping a run on the banks, Lombard
Street, never recommended a policy so
extreme. Faced with a crisis, he famously
asserted, a central bank should lend freely
at a high rate of interest against good
banking collateral. He said much more
than that, but those words—customarily
abbreviated to omit the part about the high
interest rate—are invoked to this day. No
sooner do the banks bring down a crisis on
themselves, or stock prices take a tumble,
than the call goes out for the Federal
Reserve to infuse the market with emer-
gency credit. In his memoir of the Great
Recession, The Courage to Act, Ben S.
Bernanke, chairman of the Federal Reserve
from 2006 to 2014, cited Bagehot more fre-
quently than any living economist.
Bagehot was a banker, a man of letters
and a financial journalist; most famously,
he edited the Economist. But he was no
economist himself—that is, he made no
original contribution to the body of eco-
nomic theory.
Walter Bagehot
It is a comment on the nature of eco-
nomics as much as it is on the genius of
Bagehot that his dicta on central banking
continue to hold sway almost a century
and a half after he propounded them. In
the physical sciences, progress is cumula-
tive; we stand on the shoulders of giants.
In economics, the most ostensibly rigor-
ous of the social sciences, progress—and
error, too—are cyclical; we keep stepping
on the same rakes.
There is a misconception that Bagehot
originated the idea of a lender of last
resort. It’s obvious he could not have
done so; Jeremiah Harman and his fellow
directors were doing more than Bage-
hot would later recommend two months
before the author of Lombard Street was
even born. He did, however, popularize
and legitimize the proposition, controver-
sial at the time but now taken as revealed
truth, that a central bank owed a public
duty to private persons dealing with large
sums of money. Unfortunately, he seri-
ously underestimated the extent to which
this supposed obligation would induce
people to take risks they would not oth-
erwise accept in the absence of expected
government help.
Perhaps Bagehot himself would agree.
He believed—at least, at age 39, when a
monetarily astute friend took the trouble
to make a careful inventory of his views—
that money was gold and silver and that
alone. All forms of currency, including the
notes of the Bank of England, were credit
instruments, no different than personal
checks, from which it followed that the
government had no business interven-
ing in the business of banking. Bagehot
came to modify his ideas about financial
regulation—but, unacknowledged by the
many who approvingly quote him on the
imperative of central bank crisis man-
agement, he never changed his publicly
expressed view about the gold standard or
the abomination of fiat currency.
Bagehot was not the only virtuoso
writer on money and banking in 19th-
century England: Karl Marx, London cor-
respondent for the New York Tribune, was
an accomplished financial reporter (bear
markets brought out the best in him).
George Goschen’s brilliant matched set
of essays, “Two Percent” and “Seven Per-
cent,” can be read for sheer pleasure—no
small feat considering the subject matter
is interest rates. Yet Bagehot—eclectic,
fearless, aphoristic, prolific—stands apart.
The 20th-century American journal-
ist A.J. Liebling said of himself that he
wrote faster than anyone who wrote bet-
ter, and better than anyone who wrote
faster. Bagehot made no such claim—it
would have been un-English. But with
a glance at periodical journalism in the
1850s, 1860s and 1870s, the boast would
have been defensible.
An adviser to statesmen, notably the
Liberal parliamentarian and long-serving
prime minister William E. Gladstone, he
himself failed to win election to Parlia-
ment in three attempts. Nor did he make a
fortune in the City of London. His writing
is what secured his reputation. As a finan-
cial journalist, the editor of the Economist
possessed another, apolitical virtue: his
paper was evidently incorruptible.
Bagehot himself, like many in the age
before antibiotics, was susceptible to bron-
chial disease—yet during the period of his
worst illness, he produced his most cele-
brated work. In sickness or health, he wrote
as few have ever written, before or since.
James Grant, financial journalist and
historian, is the founder and editor of
Grant’s Interest Rate Observer, a twice-
monthly journal of the investment mar-
kets. His book, The Forgotten Depres-
sion, 1921: The Crash That Cured Itself, a
history of America’s last governmentally
unmedicated business-cycle downturn,
won the 2015 Hayek Prize of the Manhat-
tan Institute for Policy Research.
This article was reprinted from Bage-
hot: The Life and Times of the Greatest
Victorian. Copyright © 2019 by James
Grant. With permission of the publisher,
W.W. Norton & Company, Inc. All rights
reserved.
www.MoAF.org | Summer 2019 | FINANCIAL HISTORY 33