Financial History Issue 130 (Summer 2019) | Page 29

of states to police activities outside their own borders, has made governing the small-sum lending industry within a fed- eral framework especially challenging. The stickiness of the problem became apparent in the early 20th century, when states such as New York attempted to prevent lend- ers from charging their residents more than the state’s maximum interest rate of 6% per year. Lenders soon discovered a loophole, however, setting up shop in neighboring states with lax usury laws and sending money and legal documents to borrowers through the mail. The differ- ences in how each state treated the same transaction created incentives for lenders to shift the legal location of their transac- tions in order to escape unfavorable regu- lations, a process known as “regulatory arbitrage.” So began a game of whack-a-mole, as restrictive states beat down one form of illegal lending only to find another pop- ping up in a different corner. State-by- state campaigns for the adoption of uni- form lending laws represented one means to combat arbitrage and rein in high-rate lenders. Even in the absence of a uniform or model law, states also learned from one another as they drafted and updated their lending rules, with states such as New York leading the charge. And, over the course of the century, the states made much progress, with many adopting uniform rules for small cash loans and imitating one another’s laws on credit sales. But they found themselves almost back at square one by the early 1980s, when a United States Supreme Court decision and subsequent legislative changes further limited state authority over national banks and the small-sum lenders that partnered with them. Second, governing small loans has been difficult because policymakers have struggled to draw appropriate regula- tory categories, with the goal of treating similar activities similarly and different activities differently. This line-drawing or categorization problem has taken several different forms over the course of the past century. For example, policymakers have been unable to decide whether small loans should be regulated just like other forms of credit or merit their own specially tailored rules. Before the rise of the small- sum cash lending business in the 1890s, the law did not draw a distinction between big loans and small ones. The same usury laws applied across the board; only pawn- shops were subject to a special set of regu- lations. But in the 1910s, the drafters of the Uniform Small Loan Law proposed that small cash loans—defined as loans under $300—should be governed by their own rules, which would allow charges greater than those permitted under most state usury laws. Proponents of the law persua- sively argued that a higher rate of charge was necessary for small-sum lenders to recoup their fixed administrative costs, manage the risks of small-sum lending and earn a profit. Although the uniform law was widely adopted in the 1920s and 30s, it also pro- voked strong opposition from populist politicians like Mayor Fiorello LaGuardia of New York City, who claimed that the law permitted “legalized usury” and was a boon to the small loan “racket.” LaGuardia saw no need to allow small- sum lenders to charge higher rates than those permitted for commercial banks. Since then, lawmakers have vacillated between two poles, sometimes treating small loans as a special category of debt and sometimes regulating them just like any other form of consumer credit. Policymakers confronted a similar cat- egorization puzzle when deciding how to regulate cash loans and the sale of goods on credit. They wrestled with whether or not the law should distinguish between these two types of transactions, and the related questions of what constitutes a “loan” or “interest” on a loan. At the beginning of the 20th century, the law drew a sharp distinction between interest on a cash loan, which was strictly limited in most states, and the charge for a sale of goods on the installment plan, which was not. The different legal treatment of these two forms of lending then cre- ated incentives for lenders to evade unfa- vorable regulations by disguising a cash loan as a credit sale. Lenders regularly engaged in this form of regulatory arbi- trage, which put pressure on policymakers to discard longstanding legal distinctions between the two transactions. As a result, the laws governing cash loans and credit sales slowly converged over the course of the past century. Yet the distinction between sales credit and cash loans did not disappear entirely, as reflected in the different legal treatment of payday loans versus rent-to-own transactions. Finally, small-sum loans have been especially tricky to govern because their regulation has been bound up with the problems of poverty and poor relief, which have compounded the complexity of the puzzle. To policymakers, small-sum lending has exemplified both the promise and the perils of modern American capi- talism for low-income households. On the one hand, small loans have promised low-wage workers a measure of indepen- dence from state support and entry into the growing consumer economy. Credit has served as a private safety net, allow- ing workers to manage financial shortfalls and make big-ticket purchases without the aid of public welfare or private charity. On the other hand, workers’ need to bor- row has also symbolized the failure of the economic system to lift up all households. The high demand for small loans has repeatedly made clear that the rising tide of American prosperity has left some boats grounded on the shore. Furthermore, onerous debts may increase demands on the state for poor relief, turning self- supporting families into public charges. Critics have labeled the business a “racket in human misery” and the purveyors of these products “loan sharks.” Thus, the link between small loans and poverty has justified both tightening and loosening the reins on the lending industry, pulling poli- cymakers in opposing directions. At some moments, policymakers have supported the small loan industry; at other times, they have treated small loans like a species of vice, unsavory and barely tolerated. Which impulse predominates at any given moment has depended, in part, on which lenders serve as the public face of the industry and how they encounter reformers and policymakers—as partners in formulating regulation or as adversaries in litigation. Attitudes have also changed over time depending on public awareness of the peculiar economics of small-sum lending, the availability of other sources of credit and their regulation, levels of public concern about poverty and prevail- ing ideas about the proper relationship between the state and the market. These changing ideas and attitudes, combined with the work of consumer advocates, www.MoAF.org  |  Summer 2019  |  FINANCIAL HISTORY  27